Global Depression 2006---? (2900 words) Gavin R. Putland - 04.12.2005 13:23
Assets ain't assets; Taxes ain't taxes; The speculative motive; Blowing bubbles; The cause of recessions; The remedy; Self-funding infrastructure; The biggest bubble in history; The U.S. dollar bubble; Soft on terrorism; Rogue states; End-game. GLOBAL DEPRESSION 2006---? Gavin R. Putland ( http://grputland.com) December 4, 2005 ASSETS AIN'T ASSETS One cannot understand economic downturns -- let alone prevent them -- without understanding certain facts about asset markets. First of all, one must understand that the assets conventionally grouped under the heading "means of production" actually fall into TWO categories: * Assets that taxpayers can neither create nor destroy nor move out of the taxing jurisdiction are LAND-LIKE assets. * The rest -- that is, assets that taxpayers can move and/or destroy and/or refrain from creating -- may be called (for want of a better analogy) HOUSE-LIKE assets. By this terminology, HOUSE-LIKE assets used as means of production include not only fixed structures, but also industrial and commercial equipment (fixed or movable) and stock in trade. The great classical economists from Adam Smith (1723-1790) to Max Hirsch (1853-1909) called such assets CAPITAL. Because the production of capital adds to the total wealth of humanity, and because the PROFITS from capital are an incentive to produce it, humanity gains from the private ownership of house-like assets and the private retention of profits derived therefrom. LAND-LIKE assets include land (not buildings), other natural resources (which cannot be created by human effort), and statutory monopolies and limited licenses (which can be created only by governments, not by taxpayers). Returns on land-like assets, net of the demands of labor and capital, are called ECONOMIC RENT [1]. From the viewpoint of taxpayers, land-like assets cannot be PRODUCED, but can only be ACQUIRED. Acquiring an asset that cannot be produced adds nothing to the total assets of humanity. While the economic rent received from a land-like asset may be partly contingent on the application of labor and capital, it accrues to the owner AS OWNER even if the labor and capital are applied by others, and is therefore not an incentive to do anything except ACQUIRE the asset. Thus the argument justifying the private retention of returns on house-like assets is NOT APPLICABLE to land-like assets. TAXES AIN'T TAXES A HOLDING TAX is a periodic tax on ownership of an asset -- in contrast to a TRANSACTION TAX, which applies to (e.g.) changes of ownership. All transaction taxes impede commerce. All taxes on house-like assets reduce the incentive to produce capital. These effects hinder production and therefore raise prices, fueling inflation and increasing the dismally-named NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT, which is the minimum unemployment rate consistent with non-accelerating inflation. But HOLDING TAXES ON LAND-LIKE ASSETS have none of these ill effects provided that the taxes take no more than the economic rent, which is NOT an incentive for production. THE SPECULATIVE MOTIVE An increase in demand for LAND-LIKE assets cannot be offset by an increase in private production. And indeed the effective demand for land-like assets tends to increase due to population growth, economic growth (which increases capacity to pay for the assets), and provision of infrastructure (which increases the amenity of certain types of assets, especially land). So land-like assets tend to appreciate in real terms. This causes SPECULATIVE DEMAND for land-like assets as individuals and firms buy assets in the hope of reselling them for higher prices, or try to save money by early acquisition of assets that they intend to use later. BLOWING BUBBLES In a RATIONAL market, the CAPITALIZED (or "lump-sum") value of a land-like asset is the DISCOUNTED PRESENT VALUE of the future rent stream. (That is, the capitalized value is the lump sum that would yield an interest stream equal to the rent for the same risk, or the sum of the future rental payments individually discounted for time and risk.) But speculation tends to make the market IRRATIONAL. When people see prices rising, they want to buy into the market. In so doing, they accelerate the rise in prices, inducing more people to buy in, and so on, causing a speculative BUBBLE -- that is, a state in which prices are decoupled from rents and are supported solely by the circular argument that prices will continue to rise. Eventually the illusion becomes unsustainable and prices stop rising, taking away the alleged justification for current prices, and so on: the bubble BURSTS. But eventually the natural appreciation of land-like assets leads to a new bubble in the same asset class. So the market for any land-like asset class is CYCLIC. THE CAUSE OF RECESSIONS A bursting bubble in a particular asset market has two counteracting effects. On the one hand, it drives investors away from that asset class and, by default, towards some other asset class that may also be susceptible to bubbles. On the other hand, those who have invested heavily in the collapsed market must reduce their expenditure, and some (most likely those who have bought their assets with borrowed money) become insolvent. As one agent's expenditure is another's income, and as one agent's debt is another's asset, a chain reaction ensues, reducing the funds available for investment in other asset markets, possibly causing them to collapse, and so on. After an isolated bubble-burst, the former effect tends to dominate; thus the land burst of the mid 1920s led to a stock-market bubble [2] and the stock-market crash of 1987 led to a land bubble. But when that second bubble bursts, the cumulative belt-tightening and bad debt tend to cause a recession; thus the stock-market crash of 1929 led to the Great Depression, and the land burst of 1989 led to the recession of 1990-91. In short, a burst in one asset market interferes with the cycles of other markets, sometimes pushing them out of synchronism by encouraging secondary bubbles, and sometimes drawing them into synchronism by triggering further bursts (and a recession). This mutual interference, complicated by external shocks, makes it difficult to discern the autonomous cycles of some asset classes, and causes irregularities in cycles that can be more easily discerned. The clearest cycles are the residential land cycle (typically 9 years in duration) and the commercial land cycle (typically 18 years). The exceptional size and unique importance of the land market mean that a bursting land bubble is the most reliable SINGLE predictor of a recession [3]; in particular, the global recessions of 1974-5, 1981-2, and 1990-91 were heralded by bursting "property" bubbles, i.e. land bubbles. THE REMEDY To prevent recessions, we must prevent speculative bubbles. This is done by imposing a sufficiently heavy HOLDING TAX ON LAND-LIKE ASSETS in lieu of taxes on transactions and house-like assets. If this holding tax is based on capitalized values or changes in capitalized values, it reduces the attractiveness of "capital gains" and forces speculators to consider the tax implications before bidding up prices. If it is based on changes in rental values, it directly reduces the changes in after-tax rents that translate into "capital gains". The heavier the holding tax, the more productively the owner must use the asset in order to cover the tax, and the less attractive it is to hold the asset for PURELY speculative purposes. SELF-FUNDING INFRASTRUCTURE To share in the benefit of a public infrastructure project, one must live or do business in the area served by the infrastructure, for which purpose one must have access to the real estate in that area. Hence the economic benefit of the project is measured by the UPLIFT IN LAND VALUES in that area. If the benefit exceeds the cost, the cost can be covered by reclaiming only PART of the benefit through the tax system, leaving the rest of the benefit as a windfall for property owners in the affected area, without burdening the taxpayers outside that area. In this case the windfall does not come at anyone else's expense, but is part of the overall increase in human welfare attributable to the project. Any holding tax based on CAPITALIZED land values indeed reclaims only PART of the benefit of an infrastructure project. When such a tax is in place, property owners' tax bills do not increase unless their land values do, and their land values do not increase unless, in the judgment of the market, the owners are better off in spite of the tax. If the tax is based only on CHANGES in capitalized values, property owners do not lose even in the initial INTRODUCTION of the tax. The higher the marginal rate of the tax, the greater the range of public projects that will pay for themselves through uplifts in land values, hence the greater the number of projects that will proceed FOR THE BENEFIT OF PROPERTY OWNERS -- and the faster the rate at which old taxes can be reduced or abolished, thanks to the surplus revenue caused by projects whose benefit/cost ratios exceed the self-funding threshold. Property owners should therefore welcome land taxation as a means of investing in public projects that return profits in the form of SUSTAINABLY higher property values -- not bubbles. Unfortunately their self-interest has not been so enlightened. THE BIGGEST BUBBLE IN HISTORY The first years of the 21st century were marked by a global property bubble. The inevitable burst began in Australia in early 2004. It has spread to the British Isles and Europe, and in due course must reach the United States [4]. Although this global bubble was confined to "housing" (i.e. residential land), it was the biggest asset bubble in history in terms of the combined GDPs of the affected countries [5] -- and that measure fails to account for the number and economic weight of the countries involved. The bigger the bubble, the bigger the burst. The bigger the burst, the bigger the recession. But even that is understating the problem. THE U.S. DOLLAR BUBBLE For half a century the U.S. dollar has been the de facto international currency. So the growth in international trade causes growth in the global demand for U.S. dollars, allowing the U.S. to export dollars -- which cost nothing to produce -- and receive real goods and services in return. That is how the U.S. manages to import 50 percent more goods and services than it exports [6]. When the exported dollars are invested, they can be invested only in U.S. assets, creating a demand for U.S. Treasury Bills without high interest rates, and inflating the price/earnings ratios of U.S. property, stocks, bonds and bills. So the value of the U.S. dollar is out of proportion to its earning capacity (yields on dollar-denominated assets). That is one characteristic of a BUBBLE. The U.S. dollar is also the dominant currency -- and until November 2000 was the exclusive currency -- for international trading in oil. Hence the reinvestment of exported dollars in U.S. assets is sometimes called RECYCLING OF PETRODOLLARS. Any increase in the global demand for oil or the price of oil causes a corresponding increase in global demand for the U.S. dollar and boosts its value, protecting the U.S. economy against the inflationary effect of higher global oil prices. Such appreciation of the dollar allows the U.S. to increase its trade deficit -- and makes U.S. goods and services less competitive, CAUSING the said increase in the trade deficit. In 1971 the U.S. dollar ceased to be backed by gold. The U.S. trade deficit appeared in the late 1970s, increased temporarily in the mid 1980s, and began its present uncontrolled blowout in about 1997. These developments made the dollar's position increasingly dependent on its use in the oil trade, so that the argument supporting the dollar became increasingly circular: dollars would buy oil because oil exporters would accept dollars because dollars would buy other products because exporters of other products would accept dollars because dollars would buy oil! Valuation by circular argument is another characteristic of a BUBBLE. One thing that could burst the bubble is a credible alternative to the dollar -- such as the euro. SOFT ON TERRORISM In November 2000, Iraq began selling oil for euros instead of U.S. dollars. The following year, the new U.S. administration was so busy looking for excuses to attack Iraq that it ignored multiple warnings about al Qaeda, and was consequently caught flat-footed on September 11 [7]. When Iraqi oil exports resumed after the U.S.-led invasion, payments were again in dollars [8]. But this situation will not necessarily continue if U.S. forces are withdrawn. ROGUE STATES Iran expressed interest in the euro from 1999, and had converted most of its currency reserves to euros by late 2002. In 2003, Iran began accepting payment in euros for oil exports to Europe and Asia. In mid 2004, Iran announced that it would establish a euro-denominated international oil bourse (exchange), which is now due to start trading by March 2006 [9,10]. Since September 2000, Venezuela and 13 other Latin-American countries have entered into barter agreements whereby Venezuela sells oil for goods and services instead of dollars. In mid 2005, Venezuela decided to move its currency reserves out of U.S. banks and liquidate its investments in U.S. Treasury securities. By early October, about 60 percent of its reserves had been converted to euros [11]. In 2004, Syria and Iraq signed a barter agreement whereby Iraq would supply crude oil in return for refined petroleum products, without using U.S. dollars [12]. Russia and Norway, on the edge of the Eurozone, have no reason to keep selling oil exclusively for U.S. dollars. Japan and China will not keep accumulating dollar reserves forever in order to finance the ballooning U.S. trade deficit. END-GAME Given that the value of the U.S. dollar must fall, nobody wants to be the last sucker holding dollars. Therefore any perception that the crash is imminent will trigger selling of dollars in an effort to pre-empt the crash. That selling will amplify the perception, causing more selling, and so on; so the perception will become reality. Worse, the rush to sell dollars will extend to dollar-denominated assets, including U.S. property, stocks, bonds and bills. So the burst of the dollar bubble may be the trigger for the expected burst of the U.S. property bubble -- among other things. If, on the contrary, the U.S. property bubble bursts of its own accord, the falling value of this class of dollar-denominated assets will reduce the attractiveness of holding dollars. Worse, the recession precipitated by the property burst will bring down other dollar-denominated asset markets. If the initial collapse of the U.S. property market is not enough to prick the dollar bubble, the ensuing collapse of other dollar-denominated asset markets will certainly be enough, and the dollar crash in turn will drive further selling of dollar-denominated assets. In either case, there will be a multiple burst involving not only the global property bubble, which is already deflating outside the U.S., but also the U.S. dollar bubble and every other asset bubble that has been pumped up by recycled petrodollars. The bigger the burst, the bigger the recession. ---------------------------------------------------------------- NOTES [1] The so-called "rent" of real property comprises the rent of the land plus the hire of any building(s) attached to the land; only the former is economic rent. The so-called "rent" of a vehicle is not economic rent, but a return on capital. [2] Most corporate shares are PARTLY backed by land-like assets. Moreover, the speed with which shares can be traded, relative to the speed with which they can be created and destroyed, makes their behavior land-like in the short term. [3] No person can live, and no business can trade, without access to land. Moreover, a land bubble tends to be accompanied by a construction boom (as buyers try to justify the exorbitant prices paid for sites) and a consumption binge (as owners borrow against inflated land values to buy goods and services). These MULTIPLIER EFFECTS work in reverse when the bubble bursts. Because of the long transaction times in the land market, a burst is initially manifested as slower sales rather than lower prices, allowing sellers and their agents to pretend that the market has "plateaued" when in fact it has crashed. This state of denial worsens the liquidity crisis that follows the crash. [4] THE ECONOMIST, November 8, 2005; http://economist.com/finance/displayStory.cfm?story_id=5132938 . [5] THE ECONOMIST, June 16, 2005; http://economist.com/opinion/displayStory.cfm?story_id=4079458 , http://economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=4079027 . [6] "America's trade deficit with China is 28% higher than America's total oil import bill... US imports of industrial supplies, capital goods, automotive vehicles, and consumer goods all exceed US oil imports." -- Paul Craig Roberts, "Still No Jobs", COUNTERPUNCH, November 8, 2005, http://counterpunch.org/roberts11082005.html . [7] Benjamin DeMott, "Whitewash as Public Service: How the 9/11 Commission Report defrauds the nation", HARPER'S, October 2004, http://harpers.org/WhitewashAsPublicService.html . [8] William Clark et al., "U.S. Dollar vs. the Euro: Another Reason for the Invasion of Iraq", PROJECT CENSORED, #19 for 2002-3, http://projectcensored.org/publications/2004/19.html ; 5 refs. [9] William Clark et al., "Iran's New Oil Trade System Challenges U.S. Currency ", PROJECT CENSORED, #9 for 2004-5, http://projectcensored.org/censored_2006/index.htm#9 ; 5 refs. [10] Cóilín Nunan, "Petrodollar or Petroeuro? A new source of global conflict", FEASTA REVIEW No.2, http://www.feasta.org/documents/review2/nunan.htm ; 32 refs. [11] Gregory Wilpert, "Venezuela's Central Bank Confirms it Deposited $20 Billion in Swiss Bank", VENEZUELANALYSIS.COM , Oct.5, 2005, http://venezuelanalysis.com/news.php?newsno=1777 . [12] See e.g. http://www.gasandoil.com/goc/news/ntm43368.htm . ---------------------------------------------------------------- Copyright (c) Prosper Australia ( http://prosper.org.au , http://earthsharing.org.au , http://lvrg.org.au). Permission is given to forward, copy, translate, and otherwise publish this work for non-commercial purposes provided that the work remains intact and includes this copyright notice. Website: http://grputland.com |